Marx
in the Mirror of Globalization By
Peter Hudis
Britannica.com
One
interesting—some would say surprising—aspect of the
ongoing discussions and debates about globalization is the renewed
interest being shown in the ideas of Karl Marx, which only recently
seemed to have been consigned to the dustbin of history. In the
journalistic and academic worlds alike, a number of reappraisals
of Marx's work are appearing that identify the 19th-century thinker
as "the prophet of globalization" because of his focus
on capital's inherent drive for self-expansion and technological
innovation on the one hand and its tendency to exacerbate social
inequality and instability on the other. Even some of globalization's
most fervent supporters note the importance of Marx's work for anticipating
the imbalances and disturbances associated with the unfettered expansion
of global capital. As John Micklethwait and Adrian Wooldridge, writers
for the passionately pro-capitalist magazine The Economist, put
it in their new book A Future Perfect: The Challenge and Hidden
Promise of Globalization, "As a prophet of socialism, Marx
may be kaput; but as a prophet of 'the universal interdependence
of nations,' as he called globalization, he can still seem startlingly
relevant...his description of globalization remains as sharp today
as it was 150 years ago."
Some may find
such talk of Marx a bit odd, given the abject failure of the communist
regimes that claimed to rule in his name. Yet as Marx scholars have
long pointed out, the communist regimes had little in common with
Marx's actual ideas. Marx opposed centralized state control of the
economy (he called those who advocated it "crude and unthinking
communists"); he passionately defended freedom of the press
(he made his debut as a radical journalist espousing it); and he
ridiculed the notion that a small "vanguard" of revolutionaries
could successfully restructure society without the democratic consent
of its citizens. If anything, the collapse of communism seems to
have spurred new interest in Marx, since it makes his predictions
concerning the global reach of capitalism seem even timelier.
Micklethwait
and Wooldridge contend that "one of the things that Marx would
recognize immediately about this particular global era is a paradox
that he spotted in the last one: The more successful globalization
becomes, the more it seems to whip up its own backlash.... The undoing
of globalization, in Marx's view, would come not just from losers
resenting the success of the winners but also from the winners themselves
losing their appetite for the battle." "There is even
a suspicion," they go on, "that globalization's psychic
energy—the uncertainly that it creates which forces companies,
governments, and people to perform better—may have a natural
stall point, a movement when people can take no more."
The tone of
much of the current discussion of Marx on the part of both supporters
and critics of globalization (for a forceful example of the latter,
see William Greider's One World, Ready or Not: The Manic Logic of
Global Capitalism) was established by John Cassidy's 1997 New Yorker
article "The Return of Karl Marx," in which he called
Marx "the next big thinker." Cassidy cited a high-placed
Wall Street investment banker who told him, "The longer I spend
time on Wall Street, and the more convinced I am that Marx was right."
What is it about
Marx's work that produces such comments? First, though Marx was
a severe critic of capitalism, few captured better its inherent
drive for technological and social innovation. As Marx saw it, capitalism
is not only about the production of material goods and services
but also about the production of value. Labor, in Marx's view, is
the source of value. And the magnitude of value, he argued, is determined
by the amount of socially necessary labor time it takes to produce
a given commodity. Marx held that there is a continual contradiction
between these two purposes: producing for material wealth and producing
for value. As productivity rises, more goods are produced in the
same unit of time, so the value of each commodity falls. The increase
in material wealth corresponds with a decline in the magnitude of
value—that is, production costs fall and prices tend to fall
as a result.
This presents
the capitalist with a knotty problem: the relative decline in the
value of each commodity risks leaving him short of the funds needed
to maintain his level of productive output. He responds by trying
to further boost productivity, since the greater the quantity of
goods produced, the better the opportunity to realize the value
of his initial investment. The best way to increase productivity
is to invest in labor-saving devices. The resulting growth in productivity,
however, reproduces the initial problem, since the increase in material
wealth leads to a further decrease in the relative value of each
commodity. Capitalism is thus based on a kind of treadmill effect,
in which the system is constantly driven toward technological innovation
regardless of its human or environmental cost. The restlessness
and drive for innovation that characterize contemporary high-tech
capitalism was long ago anticipated by Marx.
Second,
Marx held that this process of constant innovation and productive
expansion....
Second, Marx
held that this process of constant innovation and productive expansion
ultimately proceeds with disregard of national borders. The logic
of capital, he held, was to create a world market. National restrictions
on the movement of capital would eventually have to be lifted, he
argued, because capital must constantly find new markets to absorb
its ever-growing productive output.
Third, Marx
held that this process inevitably leads to a concentration and centralization
of capital at one pole and a relative immiseration of the majority
of the population at the other. Since capital is driven to increase
productivity through labor-saving devices, "dead labor"—machines,
technology—expands at a faster rate than the need for labor
power. Since workers do not own capital, but only their labor power,
social wealth gets increasingly concentrated in fewer and fewer
hands. Many consider this confirmed by the growing inequities that
follow from the globalization process, as indicated by the fact
that 225 individuals now control more wealth than half of the world's
population.
Marx
the Man
The importance
of such issues is also addressed in Francis Wheen's Karl Marx: A
Life, the first English-language Marx biography to appear in almost
two decades. In Wheen's portrait Marx the man comes across as embodying
in many respects the dialectic, a concept Marx drew from Hegel,
that every unit contains its opposite within itself. Marx came from
a family of renowned rabbis, yet showed not the slightest inclination
toward religion. He was a loving husband and father whose daughters
became important spokeswomen for socialism in their own right, yet
he once sighed "blessed be he that hath no family." He
preached the virtues of communalism and railed against egotism,
yet he was such an individualist himself that when a friend said
that she couldn't imagine him living happily in an egalitarian society,
he responded: "Neither can I. These times will come, but we
must be away by then." He spent more time thinking over the
origins, nature, and function of money than perhaps anyone, yet
he was continuously unable to earn any himself.
What is most
striking from Wheen's portrayal is Marx's gargantuan intellectual
appetite. From his earliest writings there appears no subject that
was not of interest to him—history, ancient and modern philosophy,
economics, art, literature, geology, natural science, ethnology,
and mathematics. This surely makes any effort to sum up his contribution
far from easy. So formidable was Marx's output that although he
published only a handful of books in his lifetime (including one
volume of his planned multivolume magnum opus Das Kapital), his
collected works come to more than 100 volumes, and the work of transcribing
and publishing all his writings remains to be completed even today.
Wheen approaches
his subject with considerable skepticism, especially concerning
Marx's goal of a classless society. A columnist for The Guardian,
Wheen has never considered himself sympathetic to Marxism. Yet,
he writes, "The more I studied Marx, the more astoundingly
topical he seemed to be. Today's pundits and politicians who fancy
themselves as modern thinkers like to mention the buzzword 'globalization'
at every opportunity—without realizing that Marx was already
on the case in 1848." Two issues make Marx especially relevant
in his view: one, Marx's notion that even in the most propitious
economic conditions, the laborer under capitalism is compelled to
endure overwork and "the reduction to a machine, the enslavement
to capital"; and two, Marx's insistence that once capital becomes
the predominant formation in any society, "what is truly human
becomes congealed or crystallized into a material force, while dead
objects acquire meaning, life and vigor."
None of these
recent discussions of Marx can be considered wholesale appropriations
of his legacy. The consensus on the part of most commentators is
that while Marx may have been right about the nature of capitalism,
he was less correct about the practicality of the alternative he
envisioned. Yet in light of the way Marx is gaining increased attention
from many who only a short time ago thought that history had pronounced
his ideas dead, his work may continue to illuminate the quest to
understand life under the "manic logic" of global capitalism.
As Marx once put it, "We are firmly convinced that the real
danger lies not in practical attempts, but in the theoretical elaboration
of communist ideas, for practical attempts, even mass attempts,
can be answered by cannon as soon as they become dangerous, whereas
ideas, which have conquered our intellect and taken possession of
our minds...are demons which human beings can vanquish only by submitting
to them."
Peter Hudis
is a freelance writer living in Chicago.
|